fsfe-website/documents/peru.en.txt

635 lines
36 KiB
Plaintext

Lima, 8th of April, 2002
To: Señor JUAN ALBERTO GONZÁLEZ
General Manager of Microsoft Perù
Dear Sir:
First of all, I thank you for your letter of March 25, 2002 in which
you state the official position of Microsoft relative to Bill Number
1609, Free Software in Public Administration, which is indubitably
inspired by the desire for Peru to find a suitable place in the global
technological context. In the same spirit, and convinced that we will
find the best solutions through an exchange of clear and open ideas, I
will take this opportunity to reply to the commentaries included in
your letter.
While acknowledging that opinions such as yours constitute a
significant contribution, it would have been even more worthwhile for
me if, rather than formulating objections of a general nature (which
we will analyze in detail later) you had gathered solid arguments for
the advantages that proprietary software could bring to the Peruvian
State, and to its citizens in general, since this would have allowed a
more enlightening exchange in respect of each of our positions.
With the aim of creating an orderly debate, we will assume that what
you call "open source software" is what the Bill defines as "free
software", since there exists software for which the source code is
distributed together with the program, but which does not fall within
the definition established by the Bill; and that what you call
"commercial software" is what the Bill defines as "proprietary" or
"unfree", given that there exists free software which is sold in the
market for a price like any other good or service.
It is also necessary to make it clear that the aim of the Bill we are
discussing is not directly related to the amount of direct savings
that can by made by using free software in state institutions. That is
in any case a marginal aggregate value, but in no way is it the chief
focus of the Bill. The basic principles which inspire the Bill are
linked to the basic guarantees of a state of law, such as:
* Free access to public information by the citizen.
* Permanence of public data.
* Security of the State and citizens.
To guarantee the free access of citizens to public information, it is
indispensable that the encoding of data is not tied to a single
provider. The use of standard and open formats gives a guarantee of
this free access, if necessary through the creation of compatible free
software.
To guarantee the permanence of public data, it is necessary that the
usability and maintenance of the software does not depend on the
goodwill of the suppliers, or on the monopoly conditions imposed by
them. For this reason the State needs systems the development of which
can be guaranteed due to the availability of the source code.
To guarantee national security or the security of the State, it is
indispensable to be able to rely on systems without elements which
allow control from a distance or the undesired transmission of
information to third parties. Systems with source code freely
accessible to the public are required to allow their inspection by the
State itself, by the citizens, and by a large number of independent
experts throughout the world. Our proposal brings further security,
since the knowledge of the source code will eliminate the growing
number of programs with *spy code*.
In the same way, our proposal strengthens the security of the
citizens, both in their role as legitimate owners of information
managed by the state, and in their role as consumers. In this second
case, by allowing the growth of a widespread availability of free
software not containing *spy code* able to put at risk privacy and
individual freedoms.
In this sense, the Bill is limited to establishing the conditions
under which the state bodies will obtain software in the future, that
is, in a way compatible with these basic principles.
From reading the Bill it will be clear that once passed:
# the law does not forbid the production of proprietary software
# the law does not forbid the sale of proprietary software
# the law does not specify which concrete software to use
# the law does not dictate the supplier from whom software
will be bought
# the law does not limit the terms under which a software product
can be licensed.
What the Bill does express clearly, is that, for software to be
acceptable for the state it is not enough that it is technically
capable of fulfilling a task, but that further the contractual
conditions must satisfy a series of requirements regarding the
license, without which the State cannot guarantee the citizen adequate
processing of his data, watching over its integrity, confidentiality,
and accessibility throughout time, as these are very critical aspects
for its normal functioning.
We agree, Mr. Gonzalez, that information and communication technology
have a significant impact on the quality of life of the citizens
(whether it be positive or negative). We surely also agree that the
basic values I have pointed out above are fundamental in a democratic
state like Peru. So we are very interested to know of any other way of
guaranteeing these principles, other than through the use of free
software in the terms defined by the Bill.
As for the observations you have made, we will now go on to analyze
them in detail:
Firstly, you point out that: "1. The bill makes it compulsory for all
public bodies to use only free software, that is to say open source
software, which breaches the principles of equality before the law,
that of non-discrimination and the right of free private enterprise,
freedom of industry and of contract, protected by the constitution."
This understanding is in error. The Bill in no way affects the rights
you list; it limits itself entirely to establishing conditions for the
use of software on the part of state institutions, without in any way
meddling in private sector transactions. It is a well established
principle that the State does not enjoy the wide spectrum of
contractual freedom of the private sector, as it is limited in its
actions precisely by the requirement for transparency of public acts;
and in this sense, the preservation of the greater common interest
must prevail when legislating on the matter.
The Bill protects equality under the law, since no natural or legal
person is excluded from the right of offering these goods to the State
under the conditions defined in the Bill and without more limitations
than those established by the Law of State Contracts and Purchasing
(T.U.O. by Supreme Decree No. 012-2001-PCM).
The Bill does not introduce any discrimination whatever, since it only
establishes *how* the goods have to be provided (which is a state
power) and not *who* has to provide them (which would effectively be
discriminatory, if restrictions based on national origin, race
religion, ideology, sexual preference etc. were imposed). On the
contrary, the Bill is decidedly antidiscriminatory. This is so because
by defining with no room for doubt the conditions for the provision of
software, it prevents state bodies from using software which has a
license including discriminatory conditions.
It should be obvious from the preceding two paragraphs that the Bill
does not harm free private enterprise, since the latter can always
choose under what conditions it will produce software; some of these
will be acceptable to the State, and others will not be since they
contradict the guarantee of the basic principles listed above. This
free initiative is of course compatible with the freedom of industry
and freedom of contract (in the limited form in which the State can
exercise the latter). Any private subject can produce software under
the conditions which the State requires, or can refrain from doing
so. Nobody is forced to adopt a model of production, but if they wish
to provide software to the State, they must provide the mechanisms
which guarantee the basic principles, and which are those described in
the Bill.
By way of an example: nothing in the text of the Bill would prevent
your company offering the State bodies an office "suite", under the
conditions defined in the Bill and setting the price that you consider
satisfactory. If you did not, it would not be due to restrictions
imposed by the law, but to business decisions relative to the method
of commercializing your products, decisions with which the State is
not involved.
To continue; you note that:" 2. The bill, by making the use of open
source software compulsory, would establish discriminatory and non
competitive practices in the contracting and purchasing by public
bodies..."
This statement is just a reiteration of the previous one, and so the
response can be found above. However, let us concern ourselves for a
moment with your comment regarding "non-competitive ... practices."
Of course, in defining any kind of purchase, the buyer sets conditions
which relate to the proposed use of the good or service. From the
start, this excludes certain manufacturers from the possibility of
competing, but does not exclude them "a priori", but rather based on a
series of principles determined by the autonomous will of the
purchaser, and so the process takes place in conformance with the
law. And in the Bill it is established that *no one* is excluded from
competing as far as he guarantees the fulfillment of the basic
principles.
Furthermore, the Bill *stimulates* competition, since it tends to
generate a supply of software with better conditions of usability, and
to better existing work, in a model of continuous improvement.
On the other hand, the central aspect of competivity is the chance to
provide better choices to the consumer. Now, it is impossible to
ignore the fact that marketing does not play a neutral role when the
product is offered on the market (since accepting the opposite would
lead one to suppose that firms' expenses in marketing lack any sense),
and that therefore a significant expense under this heading can
influence the decisions of the purchaser. This influence of marketing
is in large measure reduced by the bill that we are backing, since the
choice within the framework proposed is based on the *technical
merits* of the product and not on the effort put into
commercialization by the producer; in this sense, competitiveness is
increased, since the smallest software producer can compete on equal
terms with the most powerful corporations.
It is necessary to stress that there is no position more
anti-competitive than that of the big software producers, which
frequently abuse their dominant position, since in innumerable cases
they propose as a solution to problems raised by users: "update your
software to the new version" (at the user's expense, naturally);
furthermore, it is common to find arbitrary cessation of technical
help for products, which, in the provider's judgment alone, are "old";
and so, to receive any kind of technical assistance, the user finds
himself forced to migrate to new versions (with non-trivial costs,
especially as changes in hardware platform are often involved). And as
the whole infrastructure is based on proprietary data formats, the
user stays "trapped" in the need to continue using products from the
same supplier, or to make the huge effort to change to another
environment (probably also proprietary).
You add: "3. So, by compelling the State to favor a business model
based entirely on open source, the bill would only discourage the
local and international manufacturing companies, which are the ones
which really undertake important expenditures, create a significant
number of direct and indirect jobs, as well as contributing to the
GNP, as opposed to a model of open source software which tends to have
an ever weaker economic impact, since it mainly creates jobs in the
service sector."
I do not agree with your statement. Partly because of what you
yourself point out in paragraph 6 of your letter, regarding the
relative weight of services in the context of software use. This
contradiction alone would invalidate your position. The service model,
adopted by a large number of companies in the software industry, is
much larger in economic terms, and with a tendency to increase, than
the licensing of programs.
On the other hand, the private sector of the economy has the widest
possible freedom to choose the economic model which best suits its
interests, even if this freedom of choice is often obscured
subliminally by the disproportionate expenditure on marketing by the
producers of proprietary software.
In addition, a reading of your opinion would lead to the conclusion
that the State market is crucial and essential for the proprietary
software industry, to such a point that the choice made by the State
in this bill would completely eliminate the market for these firms. If
that is true, we can deduce that the State must be subsidizing the
proprietary software industry. In the unlikely event that this were
true, the State would have the right to apply the subsidies in the
area it considered of greatest social value; it is undeniable, in this
improbable hypothesis, that if the State decided to subsidize
software, it would have to do so choosing the free over the
proprietary, considering its social effect and the rational use of
taxpayers money.
In respect of the jobs generated by proprietary software in countries
like ours, these mainly concern technical tasks of little aggregate
value; at the local level, the technicians who provide support for
proprietary software produced by transnational companies do not have
the possibility of fixing bugs, not necessarily for lack of technical
capability or of talent, but because they do not have access to the
source code to fix it. With free software one creates more technically
qualified employment and a framework of free competence where success
is only tied to the ability to offer good technical support and
quality of service, one stimulates the market, and one increases the
shared fund of knowledge, opening up alternatives to generate services
of greater total value and a higher quality level, to the benefit of
all involved: producers, service organizations, and consumers.
It is a common phenomenon in developing countries that local software
industries obtain the majority of their takings in the service sector,
or in the creation of "ad hoc" software. Therefore, any negative
impact that the application of the Bill might have in this sector will
be more than compensated by a growth in demand for services (as long
as these are carried out to high quality standards). If the
transnational software companies decide not to compete under these new
rules of the game, it is likely that they will undergo some decrease
in takings in terms of payment for licenses; however, considering that
these firms continue to allege that much of the software used by the
State has been illegally copied, one can see that the impact will not
be very serious. Certainly, in any case their fortune will be
determined by market laws, changes in which cannot be avoided; many
firms traditionally associated with proprietary software have already
set out on the road (supported by copious expense) of providing
services associated with free software, which shows that the models
are not mutually exclusive.
With this bill the State is deciding that it needs to preserve certain
fundamental values. And it is deciding this based on its sovereign
power, without affecting any of the constitutional guarantees. If
these values could be guaranteed without having to choose a particular
economic model, the effects of the law would be even more
beneficial. In any case, it should be clear that the State does not
choose an economic model; if it happens that there only exists one
economic model capable of providing software which provides the basic
guarantee of these principles, this is because of historical
circumstances, not because of an arbitrary choice of a given model.
Your letter continues: "4. The bill imposes the use of open source
software without considering the dangers that this can bring from the
point of view of security, guarantee, and possible violation of the
intellectual property rights of third parties."
Alluding in an abstract way to "the dangers this can bring", without
specifically mentioning a single one of these supposed dangers, shows
at the least some lack of knowledge of the topic. So, allow me to
enlighten you on these points.
On security:
National security has already been mentioned in general terms in the
initial discussion of the basic principles of the bill. In more
specific terms, relative to the security of the software itself, it is
well known that all software (whether proprietary or free) contains
errors or "bugs" (in programmers' slang). But it is also well known
that the bugs in free software are fewer, and are fixed much more
quickly, than in proprietary software. It is not in vain that numerous
public bodies responsible for the IT security of state systems in
developed countries require the use of free software for the same
conditions of security and efficiency.
What is impossible to prove is that proprietary software is more
secure than free, without the public and open inspection of the
scientific community and users in general. This demonstration is
impossible because the model of proprietary software itself prevents
this analysis, so that any guarantee of security is based only on
promises of good intentions (biased, by any reckoning) made by the
producer itself, or its contractors.
It should be remembered that in many cases, the licensing conditions
include Non-Disclosure clauses which prevent the user from publicly
revealing security flaws found in the licensed proprietary product.
In respect of the guarantee:
As you know perfectly well, or could find out by reading the "End User
License Agreement" of the products you license, in the great majority
of cases the guarantees are limited to replacement of the storage
medium in case of defects, but in no case is compensation given for
direct or indirect damages, loss of profits, etc... If as a result of
a security bug in one of your products, not fixed in time by
yourselves, an attacker managed to compromise crucial State systems,
what guarantees, reparations and compensation would your company make
in accordance with your licensing conditions? The guarantees of
proprietary software, inasmuch as programs are delivered ``AS IS'',
that is, in the state in which they are, with no additional
responsibility of the provider in respect of function, in no way
differ from those normal with free software.
On Intellectual Property:
Questions of intellectual property fall outside the scope of this
bill, since they are covered by specific other laws. The model of free
software in no way implies ignorance of these laws, and in fact the
great majority of free software is covered by copyright. In reality,
the inclusion of this question in your observations shows your
confusion in respect of the legal framework in which free software is
developed. The inclusion of the intellectual property of others in
works claimed as one's own is not a practice that has been noted in
the free software community; whereas, unfortunately, it has been in
the area of proprietary software. As an example, the condemnation by
the Commercial Court of Nanterre, France, on 27th September 2001 of
Microsoft Corp. to a penalty of 3 million francs in damages and
interest, for violation of intellectual property (piracy, to use the
unfortunate term that your firm commonly uses in its publicity).
You go on to say that: "The bill uses the concept of open source
software incorrectly, since it does not necessarily imply that the
software is free or of zero cost, and so arrives at mistaken
conclusions regarding State savings, with no cost-benefit analysis to
validate its position."
This observation is wrong; in principle, freedom and lack of cost are
orthogonal concepts: there is software which is proprietary and
charged for (for example, MS Office), software which is proprietary
and free of charge (MS Internet Explorer), software which is free and
charged for (Red Hat, SuSE etc GNU/Linux distributions), software
which is free and not charged for (Apache, Open Office, Mozilla), and
even software which can be licensed in a range of combinations
(MySQL).
Certainly free software is not necessarily free of charge. And the
text of the bill does not state that it has to be so, as you will have
noted after reading it. The definitions included in the Bill state
clearly *what* should be considered free software, at no point
referring to freedom from charges. Although the possibility of savings
in payments for proprietary software licenses are mentioned, the
foundations of the bill clearly refer to the fundamental guarantees to
be preserved and to the stimulus to local technological
development. Given that a democratic State must support these
principles, it has no other choice than to use software with publicly
available source code, and to exchange information only in standard
formats.
If the State does not use software with these characteristics, it will
be weakening basic republican principles. Luckily, free software also
implies lower total costs; however, even given the hypothesis (easily
disproved) that it was more expensive than proprietary software, the
simple existence of an effective free software tool for a particular
IT function would oblige the State to use it; not by command of this
Bill, but because of the basic principles we enumerated at the start,
and which arise from the very essence of the lawful democratic State.
You continue: "6. It is wrong to think that Open Source Software is
free of charge. Research by the Gartner Group (an important
investigator of the technological market recognized at world level)
has shown that the cost of purchase of software (operating system and
applications) is only 8% of the total cost which firms and
institutions take on for a rational and truly beneficial use of the
technology. The other 92% consists of: installation costs, enabling,
support, maintenance, administration, and down-time."
This argument repeats that already given in paragraph 5 and partly
contradicts paragraph 3. For the sake of brevity we refer to the
comments on those paragraphs. However, allow me to point out that your
conclusion is logically false: even if according to Gartner Group the
cost of software is on average only 8% of the total cost of use, this
does not in any way deny the existence of software which is free of
charge, that is, with a licensing cost of zero.
In addition, in this paragraph you correctly point out that the
service components and losses due to down-time make up the largest
part of the total cost of software use, which, as you will note,
contradicts your statement regarding the small value of services
suggested in paragraph 3. Now the use of free software contributes
significantly to reduce the remaining life-cycle costs. This reduction
in the costs of installation, support etc. can be noted in several
areas: in the first place, the competitive service model of free
software, support and maintenance for which can be freely contracted
out to a range of suppliers competing on the grounds of quality and
low cost. This is true for installation, enabling, and support, and in
large part for maintenance. In the second place, due to the
reproductive characteristics of the model, maintenance carried out for
an application is easily replicable, without incurring large costs
(that is, without paying more than once for the same thing) since
modifications, if one wishes, can be incorporated in the common fund
of knowledge. Thirdly, the huge costs caused by non-functioning
software ("blue screens of death", malicious code such as virus,
worms, and trojans, exceptions, general protection faults and other
well-known problems) are reduced considerably by using more stable
software; and it is well known that one of the most notable virtues of
free software is its stability.
You further state that: "7. One of the arguments behind the bill is
the supposed freedom from costs of open-source software, compared with
the costs of commercial software, without taking into account the fact
that there exist types of volume licensing which can be highly
advantageous for the State, as has happened in other countries."
I have already pointed out that what is in question is not the cost of
the software but the principles of freedom of information,
accessibility, and security. These arguments have been covered
extensively in the preceding paragraphs to which I would refer you.
On the other hand, there certainly exist types of volume licensing
(although unfortunately proprietary software does not satisfy the
basic principles). But as you correctly pointed out in the immediately
preceding paragraph of your letter, they only manage to reduce the
impact of a component which makes up no more than 8% of the total.
You continue: "8. In addition, the alternative adopted by the bill (I)
is clearly more expensive, due to the high costs of software
migration, and (II) puts at risk compatibility and interoperability of
the IT platforms within the State, and between the State and the
private sector, given the hundreds of versions of open source software
on the market."
Let us analyze your statement in two parts. Your first argument, that
migration implies high costs, is in reality an argument in favor of
the Bill. Because the more time goes by, the more difficult migration
to another technology will become; and at the same time, the security
risks associated with proprietary software will continue to
increase. In this way, the use of proprietary systems and formats will
make the State ever more dependent on specific suppliers. Once a
policy of using free software has been established (which certainly,
does imply some cost) then on the contrary migration from one system
to another becomes very simple, since all data is stored in open
formats. On the other hand, migration to an free software context
implies no more costs than migration between two different proprietary
software contexts, which invalidates your argument completely.
The second argument refers to "problems in interoperability of the IT
platforms within the State, and between the State and the private
sector" This statement implies a certain lack of knowledge of the way
in which free software is built, which does not maximize the
dependence of the user on a particular platform, as normally happens
in the realm of proprietary software. Even when there are multiple
free software distributions, and numerous programs which can be used
for the same function, interoperability is guaranteed as much by the
use of standard formats, as required by the bill, as by the
possibility of creating interoperable software given the availability
of the source code.
You then say that: "9. The majority of open source code does not offer
adequate levels of service nor the guarantee from recognized
manufacturers of high productivity on the part of the users, which has
led various public organizations to retract their decision to go with
an open source software solution and to use commercial software in its
place."
This observation is without foundation. In respect of the guarantee,
your argument was rebutted in the response to paragraph 4. In respect
of support services, it is possible to use free software without them
(just as also happens with proprietary software), but anyone who does
need them can obtain support separately, whether from local firms or
from international corporations, again just as in the case of
proprietary software.
On the other hand, it would contribute greatly to our analysis if you
could inform us about free software projects *established* in public
bodies which have already been abandoned in favor of proprietary
software. We know of a good number of cases where the opposite has
taken place, but not know of any where what you describe has taken
place.
You continue by observing that: "10. The bill discourages the
creativity of the Peruvian software industry, which invoices 40
million US$/year, exports 4 million US$ (10th in ranking among
non-traditional exports, more than handicrafts) and is a source of
highly qualified employment. With a law that encourages the use of
open source, software programmers lose their intellectual property
rights and their main source of payment."
It is clear enough that nobody is forced to commercialize their code
as free software. The only thing to take into account is that if it is
not free software, it cannot be sold to the public sector. This is not
in any case the main market for the national software industry. We
covered some questions referring to the influence of the Bill on the
generation of employment which would be both highly technically
qualified and in better conditions for competition above, so it seems
unnecessary to insist on this point.
What follows in your statement is incorrect. On the one hand, no
author of free software loses his intellectual property rights, unless
he expressly wishes to place his work in the public domain. The free
software movement has always been very respectful of intellectual
property, and has generated widespread public recognition of its
authors. Names like those of Richard Stallman, Linus Torvalds, Guido
van Rossum, Larry Wall, Miguel de Icaza, Andrew Tridgell, Theo de
Raadt, Andrea Arcangeli, Bruce Perens, Darren Reed, Alan Cox, Eric
Raymond, and many others, are recognized world-wide for their
contributions to the development of software that is used today by
millions of people throughout the world. On the other hand, to say
that the rewards for authors rights make up the main source of payment
of Peruvian programmers is in any case a guess, in particular since
there is no proof to this effect, nor a demonstration of how the use
of free software by the State would influence these payments.
You go on to say that: "11. Open source software, since it can be
distributed without charge, does not allow the generation of income
for its developers through exports. In this way, the multiplier effect
of the sale of software to other countries is weakened, and so in turn
is the growth of the industry, while Government rules ought on the
contrary to stimulate local industry."
This statement shows once again complete ignorance of the mechanisms
of and market for free software. It tries to claim that the market of
sale of non- exclusive rights for use (sale of licenses) is the only
possible one for the software industry, when you yourself pointed out
several paragraphs above that it is not even the most important
one. The incentives that the bill offers for the growth of a supply of
better qualified professionals, together with the increase in
experience that working on a large scale with free software within the
State will bring for Peruvian technicians, will place them in a highly
competitive position to offer their services abroad.
You then state that: "12. In the Forum, the use of open source
software in education was discussed, without mentioning the complete
collapse of this initiative in a country like Mexico, where precisely
the State employees who founded the project now state that open source
software did not make it possible to offer a learning experience to
pupils in the schools, did not take into account the capability at a
national level to give adequate support to the platform, and that the
software did not and does not allow for the levels of platform
integration that now exist in schools."
In fact Mexico has gone into reverse with the Red Escolar (Schools
Network) project. This is due precisely to the fact that the driving
forces behind the Mexican project used license costs as their main
argument, instead of the other reasons specified in our project, which
are far more essential. Because of this conceptual mistake, and as a
result of the lack of effective support from the SEP (Secretary of
State for Public Education), the assumption was made that to implant
free software in schools it would be enough to drop their software
budget and send them a CD ROM with Gnu/Linux instead. Of course this
failed, and it couldn't have been otherwise, just as school
laboratories fail when they use proprietary software and have no
budget for implementation and maintenance. That's exactly why our bill
is not limited to making the use of free software mandatory, but
recognizes the need to create a viable migration plan, in which the
State undertakes the technical transition in an orderly way in order
to then enjoy the advantages of free software.
You end with a rhetorical question: "13. If open source software
satisfies all the requirements of State bodies, why do you need a law
to adopt it? Shouldn't it be the market which decides freely which
products give most benefits or value?"
We agree that in the private sector of the economy, it must be the
market that decides which products to use, and no state interference
is permissible there. However, in the case of the public sector, the
reasoning is not the same: as we have already established, the state
archives, handles, and transmits information which does not belong to
it, but which is entrusted to it by citizens, who have no alternative
under the rule of law. As a counterpart to this legal requirement, the
State must take extreme measures to safeguard the integrity,
confidentiality, and accessibility of this information. The use of
proprietary software raises serious doubts as to whether these
requirements can be fulfilled, lacks conclusive evidence in this
respect, and so is not suitable for use in the public sector.
The need for a law is based, firstly, on the realization of the
fundamental principles listed above in the specific area of software;
secondly, on the fact that the State is not an ideal homogeneous
entity, but made up of multiple bodies with varying degrees of
autonomy in decision making. Given that it is inappropriate to use
proprietary software, the fact of establishing these rules in law will
prevent the personal discretion of any state employee from putting at
risk the information which belongs to citizens. And above all, because
it constitutes an up-to-date reaffirmation in relation to the means of
management and communication of information used today, it is based on
the republican principle of openness to the public.
In conformance with this universally accepted principle, the citizen
has the right to know all information held by the State and not
covered by well- founded declarations of secrecy based on law. Now,
software deals with information and is itself information. Information
in a special form, capable of being interpreted by a machine in order
to execute actions, but crucial information all the same because the
citizen has a legitimate right to know, for example, how his vote is
computed or his taxes calculated. And for that he must have free
access to the source code and be able to prove to his satisfaction the
programs used for electoral computations or calculation of his taxes.
I wish you the greatest respect, and would like to repeat that my
office will always be open for you to expound your point of view to
whatever level of detail you consider suitable.
Cordially,
DR. EDGAR DAVID VILLANUEVA NUÑEZ
Congressman of the Republic of Perù.